|
Whereas cross-sectional comparative research on monetary support for
families with children linking quantitative data on cash and tax benefits
with institutional regulations and system characteristics seems to be
well established, systematic analyses of the long-term lines of development,
however, are still lacking. This article therefore aims at analysing the
child-related elements of both instruments over a longer span of time.
Partly based on a newly accesible database, the presentation uses a descriptive
and institution-orientated approach.
Plan of article - Topics and questions tackled
Focusing on Germany (D) and five of its neighbour countries - Austria
(A), Belgium (B), France (F), the Netherlands (NL), and Switzerland (CH)
-, the following piece of research intends to compare the relative importance
of general family allowances/child benefits and to determine and evaluate
the monetary value of standard tax reliefs for dependent children. Both
time-series data from the MZES/EURODATA Family Policy Database (http://www.mzes.uni-mannheim.de/projekte/fpdb/)
as well as OECD, EUROSTAT, ILO and national statistics are used. Reference
is made to central institutional characteristics of both benefits and
tax and transfer systems. To the highest possible degree, Luxembourg (L)
as well as the three central European OECD member countries Czech Republic
(CZ), Hungary (H), and Poland (PL) are included in the analysis of the
family's income position after taxes, social contributions and cash transfers.
Whereas the monetary transfers are screened for about the last five decades
up to the mid 1990s, the qualitative and quantitative analysis of the
fiscal treatment of children has to be limited to the period 1979-1998
due to lack of comparable data before the late 1970s. The article endeavours
to provide an overview on both the empirical relevance of different types
of tax reliefs since the late 1970s and their effects on household income.
Two possible units of comparison come into play, household type and instrument
of family policy. Whereas in the first case the focus is on different
levels of disposable household income of a married single earner with
two children juxtaposed with a childless single person, the second perspective
'confronts' fiscal reliefs with cash benefits. Again the main concern
will be to identify factors related to common patterns and similar lines
of development. Additionally, the hypothesis that countries providing
rather generous cash benefits will 'score high' when it comes to alleviating
the financial burden of families by means of tax relief for children will
be tested. This contribution intends to depict the major patterns of support
for children through the national social transfer and income tax systems
as far as the benefit levels are concerned. Is it possible to assume that
there is a (coordinated) interplay of monetary transfers and fiscal reliefs
granted for children or do the two systems evolve and coexist more or
less independently? Finally, what is their combined effect on the family
income, both in a cross-country perspective and in relation to a single
person without children with the same gross earnings level?
Schemes providing cash benefits to families
A necessary precondition for comparing benefit levels and institutional
regulations amongst countries and across time is to define the precise
object of comparison. This holds for the schemes of social protection
as well as for the specific cash and tax benefits under investigation.
Table 1 lists the family benefit schemes data stem from and institutional
regulations are related to. Both their names in the official language(s)
and a translation into English are given. Entries in the column 'year
of establishment' refer to the year in which the first payment to a (sub)group
covered by the scheme was made. Given the fact that the analysis brings
together countries with different legacies as regards the concept of benefit
design, rules of financing and administrative structures, the last column
indicates to which extent the institutional fragmentation still played
a role in 1996. In all countries without a universal scheme, i.e. in Austria,
Belgium, France, Germany, Luxembourg, (the Netherlands), Poland, and Switzerland,
the by far and large most important scheme was selected.
With regard to the systems of public family support, there exists a basic
institutional difference between countries with residencerelated, universal
schemes, financed by general tax revenues on the one hand, and countries
with fragmented systems, differentiating between groups of persons according
to entitlement and benefit regulations, (co-)financed by employers' social
contributions and often administrated by social security agencies or special
funds on the other. Many of these original differences have been blurred
over the last half decade, elements of both 'ideal types' amalgamated.
Therefore the classification of countries takes into account the phase
when the family benefits were introduced and 'shaped' as well as their
present configuration. Given the numerous changes since 1950, the following
categorization is necessarily based on the dominant feature related to
the eligibility for the scheme, to the mode of financing, and to the administrative
structures during the last 50 years.
On the one hand, the Czech Republic and Hungary represent countries with
a universal scheme, dating from the socialist era and continued after
1990. The Netherlands implemented a uniform system when they integrated
the five existing schemes in 1980. Since then the child benefit is 100
percent financed by the national government. Germany started with an employmentrelated
system in the private sector in 1954, which gradually became more generalised.
'In December 1955, entitlement was extended to cover all active and nonactive
persons with three or more children. The federal government contributed
to the financing of child benefits for inactive persons. With this, family
allowances lost in fact their exclusively employmentrelated character
as early as 1955' (Bahle 2001). In 1961 a statefinanced general child
benefit for children of birth rank two was introduced, but only for families
with annual incomes below 7,200 DM. 'The next major reform in 1964 completely
reorganized the whole system: the child benefit was totally financed out
of the federal budget and the old professional compensation funds were
abolished' (Bahle 2001). In 1975 the entitlement was extended to cover
families with one child, completely independent of the income. Eight years
after having implemented the child benefit as a universal cash transfer,
benefits - except for the first child - in 1983 were once again made dependent
on income, varying between minimum and maximum amounts. In the same year,
child tax allowances were reintroduced and low-income families who could
not benefit from it received a child benefit supplement (Kindergeldzuschlag)
for each child. 'This dual system of tax and cash benefits, with deductions
for higher incomes and supplements for lower incomes, remained in force
until 1996' (Bahle 2001). Poland started with one general, employment-related
scheme, too, in 1947. Only 30 years later, selfemployed farmers also became
entitled, paid out by the Social Insurance Institution (Zaklad Ubezpieczen
Spolecznych/ZUS). Since 1990 their benefits are administered by a specific
agency, the Farmers' Social Insurance Institution (Kasa Rolniczego Ubezpieczenia
Spolecznego/KRUS). In the general scheme the child benefit was completely
financed by employers' social contributions until 1994. Since 1995, they
have been financed out of the central state budget, as in the case of
the child benefit for independent farmers.
On the other hand, Belgium, France and Luxembourg from the beginning organized
a separate scheme of social security for family benefits, exclusively
or largely financed by social contributions of employers (and self-employed).
The management of funds was conferred to specific agencies . Austria has
established a special fund for the equalisation of family burdens (Familienlastenausgleichsfonds/FLAF)
since the mid 1950s, alimented by employers' social contributions, social
contributions of self-employed and the financial participation of federal
and state governments. Here, however, no specific agency is in charge
of the benefit provision. In addition, the labour market nexus has never
been as tight as in the other countries. If the small scheme for war victims,
pensioners with small incomes and victims of crimes is left aside, the
institutional constellations in Austria and Germany are comparable. With
the exception of benefit regulations for small farmers and agricultural
workers - in force since 1952 - which apply in a uniform manner for the
whole federation, Switzerland is the only European country without a national
(framework) legislation in the sphere of family allowances. Following
Fux one can underline that 'due to the federalist organization of the
country and the predominance of the concept of subsidiarity (…), many
of the most important institutions come under the authority of the cantons,
the municipalities, or even private organizations and associations. The
system of family allowances therefore resembles a jungle of unsystematic
complexity' (Fux 2001). For the purpose of this article, it is exclusively
the family allowances funds under cantonal legislations that are reported
on.
Table 1: Family benefit schemes considered
(1950-1998)
Sources: Maucher/Bahle 2000; for CH: Fux 2001; for CZ: Cervenková
1993, Storka 1995; for H: Tárkányi, in Spéder 2001;
for L: STATEC, various years; for PL additionally: Golinowska 2001
Notes:
A: Up to 1978 the amounts paid in the subscheme for self-employed and
freelancers reached, as a rule, only about 80 to 85 percent of the benefit
rates paid in the subscheme for workers and employees.
CH: The years indicated refer to the first resp. last canton legislating
child benefits for families with two or more children, Vaud/Wallis resp.
Appenzell-Ausserrhoden. Benefits provided by cantonal family allowances
funds for families with one child were introduced between 1945 (Fribourg/Freiburg)
and 1970 (Obwalden). Striving towards a maximum of consistence with the
analyses on fiscal advantages for children as presented by the OECD, all
data refer to the canton of Zurich (Zürich), where the legislation
on the socalled 'child wage supplements' (Kinderzulagen) was enacted in
1958. This regulation applied to all children, independent from birth
rank.
CS/CZ: The year of introduction refers to the former Czechoslovakia (CS).
The scheme was continued in both the Czech (CZ) and Slovak Republic (SK)
after their separation on 01.01.1993, however.
H: In 1953 the entitlement to family allowances was extended to persons
working in agricultural cooperatives and having three or more children,
in 1966 to those with at least two children. From 1975 onwards, they received
the same amount of family allowance as workers and employees and therefore
are no longer distinguished as a specific scheme.
L: Before 01.04.1964 a distinction was made between wage and salary earners
and non-employed persons as regards the benefit rates. The family allowances
paid to the latter group only amounted to about one fifth (first child)
to about half (third to fifth child) of the benefits paid to economically
active persons.
List of other schemes (1996; H: only for period 1953-1974; NL: prior
to 1963/1979), in chronological order by year of establishment*:
A: Public service employees (Hoheitsverwaltung des Bundes; Post und Bahn;
Hoheitsverwaltung der Länder, Bezirke und Gemeinden mit mehr als
2000 Einwohnern); War victims, pensioners with small income(s), victims
of crimes (Kriegsopfer, Kleinrentner, Opfer von Verbrechen)
B: Scheme for public service employees (Service public/Openbare diensten);
Scheme for self-employed (Régime indépendants/Zelfstandigen);
Residual scheme (Régime garanti/Gewaarborgte kinderbijslag)
CH: Scheme for small farmers and agricultural workers (Familienzulageordnung
für Kleinbauern und landwirtschaftliche Arbeitnehmer/Caisses d'allocations
familiales pour petits paysans et travailleurs agricoles); Schemes for
public services employees (Familienzulageordnung für Beschäftigte
des Öffentlichen Sektors/Régime d'allocations familiales pour
le personnel du secteur public); Schemes for self-employed (Familienzulageordnung
für Selbständigerwerbende/Régime d'allocations familiales
pour les indépendants) - in 9 cantons (cf. Fux 2001)
D: Scheme for public service employees (System für Beschäftigte
im Öffentlichen Dienst)
F: Miner's scheme (Régime mineur); Personnel of public service
and other special schemes (Personnel des services publics et régimes
spéciaux); Agricultural scheme (Régime agricole)
H: Family allowances scheme for persons working in agricultural cooperatives
(Mezögazdasági termelöszövetkezeti családok)
L: Employees and civil servants (Employés et fonctionnaires); Non-employed
persons (Non-salariés). The distinction between the different schemes
was discontinued as of 01.01.1997.
NL (all completely discontinued in 1979 - as the scheme for workers and
employees in industry and commerce): Public service employees (Overheidspersoneel);
Social insurance recipients (Rentetrekkers); Small self-employed (Kleine
zelfstandigen)
PL: Self-employed farmers (Rolnicy induwidualni)
Institutional regulations
When comparing family allowances in European countries, one can identify
common properties and main lines of development shared by all of them.
One example is the question of eligibility to social protection schemes.
Over the last decades, in countries with fragmented systems the coupling
between earned employment and the entitlement to benefits became looser
and was finally withdrawn using different techniques (gradual lifting
of the clause defining this link; establishment of complementary scheme).
This obviously reduced the factual differences between all countries in
the sample. Another point is closely linked to benefit levels. Especially
since the mid 1970s, the aim of keeping up the real value of the child
benefit seems to be largely agreed upon in all countries, independent
of their institutional configuration. If we compare the tools used, it
is impossible to identify a common logic, however. Some countries use
automatic mechanisms of indexing benefit rates, based on the development
of wages or consumer prices in order to achieve a certain stability. The
Netherlands, e.g., applied a halfannual dynamisation based on the development
of the cost-of-living index in the 1990s. In Luxembourg and Belgium, shifts
in the consumer price index are used as a benchmark. Already in 1946,
France shifted from an indexation based on wages to an adaptation linked
to price increases . Prior to 1996, Germany did not follow in these footsteps,
legislating benefit revaluations only on an irregular basis. This tradition
came to an end when the dual system of child benefit and child tax allowances
had to be redefined. Since then the public transfers are directly linked
to standard of living measures. The new point of reference is the officially
determined existence minimum of children which must not be taxed and has
to be adjusted to consumer price changes. In Switzerland, benefit increases
are administered on an irregular basis, too. During the 1990s, the family
allowances paid to Hungarian families were not systematically adjusted
either. To the contrary, due to the recession their real value fell rather
dramatically . The same holds for Poland .
On the other hand, the different elements included in the design of benefit
rates created a variety of legal stipulations. In 1998, all countries
except for Austria, the Czech Republic, and Switzerland had fixed a differentiation
according to the parity of the child. Benefits increase with higher birth
rank, often with progressive rates, reaching a maximum per child at birth
rank three or four in most of the countries during the period 1950-1998.
Divergence is also produced by means of age supplements or via a system
differentiating the amount according to age groups across the integral
scale (Belgium since 1957, the Netherlands after 1982, the Czech Republic
from 1994 on). Whereas both Austria and France introduced age supplements
for one age group and redefined a second age group later, Belgium used
a differentiation system with initially six and later five age groups.
The process of integrating the five existing schemes into one general
scheme in the Netherlands in 1980 was linked to a redesign of the benefit
rates which have been differentiated according to age groups across the
whole scale since then . Finally, in 1994, the Czech system was rescheduled
completely, shifting from differentiation according to birth rank to a
differentiation according to age group. Some countries take into account
the economic resources of households as a tool for regulating entitlement.
Benefits are graded by family income or even withdrawn in case a certain
threshold is exceeded. The tendency to introduce meanstesting is especially
obvious in the three central European countries during the second phase
of the transition period after 1994. When the income thresholds were defined
by the mid 1990s, the intention to implement cost containment dominated
the public debate. Besides, the idea of a stricter targeting of social
benefits was advocated, strongly based on policy recommendations brought
forward by consultants of the IMF and the World Bank. The income test
introduced in Hungary (1996) only applies to families with not more than
two children. In the Czech Republic (1996) and Poland (1995) upper limits
have been fixed for larger families, too. France experimented with a benefit
withdrawal for well-off families in 1998; however, the income threshold
was fixed on a relatively high level. Only households with an income of
at least 25,000 FF (to be increased by 5,000 FF for every child above
birth rank 2 and 7,000 FF for double-earner households) were no longer
entitled to family allowances. Western European Countries with residence-related
universal systems do not apply, as a rule, any income test .
Table 2 sums up the main features linked to the design of benefit rates.
In taking up the guiding question to which extent the major differences
'scope of scheme' and 'mode of financing' can account for cross-country
variations, one has to conclude that no systematic correlations with the
conceptualization of benefit rates become visible. It is not even possible
to depict phase-specific patterns. A general tendency can nevertheless
be seen in the sequence of first introducing variations by birth rank
and later adding a system with amounts graded by age. This underlines
the concern shared amongst policy makers of all countries to encourage
the birth of more than two children, necessary for societal reproduction,
as well as the insight that every additional child directly reduces the
per capita disposable household income and indirectly restricts the option
to add to it labour market income earned by the spouse. The seven countries
that have implemented phase-specific variations all apply a concept which
intends to partially account for higher expenses for clothing, education,
and leisure time activities with growing age, starting with children of
primary or lower secondary school age. Linking the entitlement with the
family income can be identified as one important source of variation,
however. In Western European countries, the elements 'universalism' and
'nonapplication of income testing' are highly correlated. Since the geographical
scope has been intended and now includes three central European transformation
countries, this relationship can no longer be established. Here, income
thresholds were defined as a means of cutting down social expenditure
during the period of economic transition. A measure seemingly inevitable
in the face of growing deficits in the budgets of all public and parastatal
authorities, including the social security funds.
Table 2
Sources: Maucher/Bahle 2000; for CH: Fux 2001; for CZ: Cervenková
1993 and 1994, Storka 1995; for H: Tárkányi, in Spéder
2001; for L: STATEC, various years; for PL additionally: Golinowska 2001
Notes:
In the column 'Birth ranks on which increase is applied' the ordinal number
indicated to the left of the arrow represents the birth rank to which
a first augmentation was applied. The ordinal number to the right of the
arrow defines the birth rank up to which the maximum increase per child
was enacted. This, however, does not exclude that a higher absolute amount
per head for children of any other birth rank was paid.
CH: As for the data, the institutional regulations presented are those
in force for the canton of Zurich (Zürich), only.
PL: 'Since 1 March 2000 the family allowance is exclusively available
to families whose income per capita does not exceed 50% of average wages'
(Golinowska 2001).
Range of different age groups*:
A: 1967-1994: 10+; 1995-1998: 10-18; 19+
B: 1957-1985: 0-6; 6-10, 10-14; 14-16, 16-18; 18+, 1986-1998: 0-6, 6-12,
12-16; 16-18; 18+
CZ: 1994-1998: 0-5; 6-9; 10-14; 15-18 (regular age limit)/26 (extended
age limit, if child is in education)
L: 1977-1988: 12+; 1989-1998: 6-11; 12+
NL: 1983-1990: 0-5; 6-11; 12-17; 18-26; 1991-1998: 0-5; 6-11; 12-17; 18-24
Benefit levels
Graph 1 presents the development of the quotient of family allowances
for three children and the national income per capita for three persons.
Possible age supplements were disregarded .
Graph 1: Benefuts for three children as
share of national income per capita for three persons, 1960-1996
What becomes obvious at first sight is the relatively advantageous position
of (larger) families in Austria and Belgium. In these two countries, benefits
have always been on a level clearly above the average. For France, Luxembourg,
and the Netherlands, the benefit rates float in principle around the long-term
mean of about 6 percent. In the case of France, the value only sums up
the benefit rates for the second and third child. The hexagon (still)
is the only country in Europe that excludes families with only one child
from the provision of family allowances . Therefore, the graph only inadequately
reflects the increase attributable to the birth of a third child. France
and Luxembourg put a special 'premium' on children of birth rank 3, an
approach generally classified as pronatalist. In a comparative perspective
Germany (except for the period since 1996) and Switzerland only provide
rather moderate benefits for families with three children. The evident
increase of benefit rates across all birth ranks is linked to the reorganization
of the German system of financially equalizing family burdens, enacted
in 1996.
Looking across time, one can clearly state a tendency towards convergence,
even if non-negligible differences in relative shares still persist. Austria
and Germany show one common pattern in the sense that step changes upwards
are levelled out by continuously decreasing shares during the following
years. Whereas the step changes are related to the extension of benefits
to cover children of birth rank 1 - in Germany in 1975, in Austria in
1978 -, the monotonously reduced levels are linked to a policy which did
not (systematically) rely on the instrument of indexing benefit rates.
Revaluation rather takes place at irregular intervals. Switzerland enters
into the same group. However, the adaptations of benefit rates are rather
smooth and much more in line with the growth rates of the national economy.
The more stable development in France seemingly springs from the linkage
of consumer price increases with family benefits, too. The same holds
for Belgium , Luxembourg, and the Netherlands.
Graph 2a: Benefits for two children aged
15 as share of average gross wage of workers, 1950-2000
Graph 2a shifts the focus from the macroeconomic context to an evaluation
of the policy outcome. It compares the amount of transfer income generated
by the entitlement to family allowances for two children, aged 15, as
a share of workers' average gross wages . Given the empirical evidence
of benefit variations by age, we defined a specific age in order to minimize
possible distortions springing from the data on child benefits. The decision
to opt for age 15 takes up the (more traditional) concept of growing needs
and expenditure with increasing age, reflected in many social assistance
schemes, too . Again, distortions may not only spring from redefinitions
of the reference value, the average gross wage of a production worker,
or inconsistencies in the quantitative basis. Different relative weights
have to be seen against the background of different general wage levels
in the seven countries, too. Controlling for exchange rates and differences
in purchasing power, the wages paid e.g. in Switzerland, Germany, and
Luxembourg are comparatively high. This inevitably accounts for generally
lower rates in these countries.
If we focus on the major developments, basically the same ranking of countries
as shown above in graph 1 is being reproduced. This provides additional
support to our hypothesis stating that the differences in the relative
importance of family allowances follow a more systematic pattern. Path
dependencies cannot be overseen. Countries with originally employment-related
schemes, building on the concept of a 'family wage/salary', tend to be
more generous than countries with resident-related systems. This is especially
true for Austria, Belgium, and France. The Belgian (from 1957) and French
(from 1963) data include age supplements; this is clearly visible in graph
2b (Belgium) and in graph 2a (France). Due to the lack of raw data, in
the case of Austria the age supplements (introduced in 1967) are graphically
represented for the period from 1981 onwards, which is reflected in a
small step change. Luxembourg arrived at the higher levels only during
the last decade, however. Across all countries the smooth ups and downs
reflect a real growth or decrease in benefit rates, in the first case
partly due to indexation. The consequences of wage moderation and measures
with repercussions on social security contributions enter as an additional
factor. Their weight cannot be identified in detail in the context of
this long-term comparison, however. The evident changes in the relative
shares for Austria (1978) and Germany (1975) are related to two additional
factors: first, as mentioned above, to the inclusion of children of first
birth rank into the payment of family allowances; second, the abrupt increases
of the benefit rates coincide with a reorganized interplay of cash and
tax benefits. In both countries, the child tax allowance (Kinderfreibetrag)
was abolished in the years referred to above - a discontinuation which
was compensated for by means of increased cash benefits, however. As above,
a general tendency towards continuous convergence across all countries
in the sample, especially since the mid 1970s and after a second 'impulse'
by the mid 1990s, is clearly documented .
Graph 2b: Benefits for two children aged
15 as share of avarage gross salary of employees, 1950-2000
Especially since the 1970s, the 'employees' have become the dominant
occupational group in all (Western) European countries. Graph 2b sketches
out the family allowances paid for two children aged 15 as a share of
the average income of employees in industry and commerce. It is fairly
comparable to graph 2a. The main difference lies in a reduced scale to
represent the relative weight of family allowances; they reach a maximum
of 12 percent compared to 22 percent above, to be explained by the higher
average earned gross income of employees in relation to workers . In Austria,
Belgium, and France, family allowances accounts for about 8 to 11 percent
of the average gross salary. Even if in Germany employees reached fairly
comparable shares as late as the mid 1990s, the child benefit did not
even account for half of the transfer income, as it was the case in the
three countries mentioned above for the whole rest of the period. Switzerland,
too, shows rather modest shares. Again, Luxembourg offers constantly increasing
benefits and finally joins the 'top group' by the mid 1990s. A graph for
the Netherlands cannot be presented due to a lack of appropriate data
on employees' gross earnings.
Fiscal reliefs for children
Taking up the central elements of cross-country variation, this article
is exclusively concerned with standard childrelated tax reliefs and focuses
on the three dimensions 'existence', 'type' and 'quantitative importance'.
Far less ambitious than other pieces of comparative research , it aims
at determining the monetary equivalent of the general fiscal advantages
for children for a single family type - married single earner with two
children with gross average earnings of the average production worker
(APW) - over the last two decades .
Graph 3: Existence and type of child-related
tax reliefs as share of disposable household income of married one-earner
couple with two children, 1979-1998
It seems useful to tackle the topic with an overview on the availability,
form and relative weight of tax reliefs for children. Within the period
analysed, the large majority of countries had enacted special provisions
for dependent children in the respective income tax systems. Their main
purpose consists in (partially) accounting for the additional financial
strain, put on the family budget by children within the tax system, too.
The relative share of fiscal advantages as compared to the net family
income oscillates between 1 to 8 percent (even up to 11 percent in Germany,
1996-1998; cf. endnotes 27 and 30 for this special case). The French family
splitting scheme has a rather high additional effect, too. No data are
presented for Luxembourg. Up to the fiscal year 1990, the Grand Duchy
also relied on a family coefficent system. It allocated even larger parts
to the children than those fixed in the French income tax code . Calculations
for 1984 and 1990 showed an effect which - in relative terms - even exceeded
the advantage provided to French one-earner couples with two children
. The same holds for the phase since 1991, as indicated by estimations
for 1991 and 1998. Arriving at a quotient of about 3 percent in a long-term
perspective, Belgium, the Czech Republic, and Germany (1986-1995) occupy
a middle position. In contrast, the Hungarian and Swiss provisions did
not lift the disposable household income upwards on the scale to any extent
worth mentioning.
Additional cross-country variation is mainly produced by two other parametres
relevant for the design of tax reliefs, namely the indexation and the
grading of benefit levels. As early as 1957 the Austrian child tax allowances
were indexed according to price increases. After a phase without automatic
adjustments, Belgium inflated the tax reliefs more or less regularly during
the period 1976-1988. Since 1989 it is mandatory to adjust all amounts
relevant for taxation to inflation on an annual basis. Copying the cash
transfer systems, a subsample of countries had or still has fixed a grading
of the child-related fiscal advantages by birth rank. Again, this applies
to Austria (since 1996) and Belgium (since 1985). In this Benelux country,
the grading of the tax credit shows a clear increase from the child with
birth rank 3 onwards, inducing substantially higher tax reliefs for larger
families. In 1953, the German income tax code provided higher tax allowances
for children of birth rank 3 and 4. This differentiation was extended
to benefit the second child three years later. To our knowledge, none
of the 10 countries used the grading by age . This is not consistent with
‚common practice' in the monetary transfer schemes.
To sum it up, the picture is characterized by a great diversity of country-specific
'solutions' concerning child-related fiscal welfare. Their relative importance
to the family budget varies widely, too. If Germany as a special case
is left aside, Hungary is the only country which implemented a shift as
to the type of tax relief. It is impossible to discover a correlation
between the pattern of tax reliefs - i.e. the existence and type - and
the dominant institutional features of the family allowances schemes.
Nevertheless, it becomes evident that countries that make provisions for
a general direct monetary transfer above the average also tend to have
incorporated regulations into their income tax code which result in a
medium or relatively high standard fiscal advantage for one-earner couples
with two children. If one assumes a positive nexus between the relative
role of the two instruments of social policy, then Austria, Belgium and
France fit in this hypothesis fairly well.
Before I take up the analysis, some definitions are given. Additionally,
the empirical tax reliefs are explained with regard to country-specific
terminology and their effect. The latter aspect refers to the procedure
which determines both taxable income and tax due . Only Austria (Kinderabsetzbetrag)
and Luxembourg (modération d'impôt pour enfants) offered
a tax credit also labelled accordingly in 1998. On grounds relating to
the logic of reducing the burden on familiy incomes, the instruments used
can be classified as 'tax credits' in Belgium, France, and Germany. In
Belgium, every child gives entitlement to an additional exemption (majoration
de la tranche exonérée octroyée pour enfant(s) à
charge) to be deducted from the bottom brackets. Since 1945, France applies
a quotient system, combining a spouse (quotient conjugal/quotient-époux)
and a child (quotient-enfant) coefficient, commonly described as 'family
splitting' (quotient familial). In both countries, these regulations have
the effect of a tax credit. Pressed by a 1990-ruling of the Federal Constitutional
Court which had obliged the German legislative bodies to decide on measures
resulting in a complete exemption of children's existence minima within
a 5-year-term, they finally opted for a 'mixtum compositum' (Wingen 1997:
232) of cash and tax benefits in reshaping the system of family income
support, effective as of 01.01.1996. This construction actually extended
the 'dual system' up to the present , combining cash benefits with child
tax allowances. It provides a refundable/non-wastable tax credit (Steuervergütung),
differentiated according to birth rank, to all tax payers and builds on
a complex interplay of child benefit (Kindergeld) and child tax allowance
(Kinderfreibetrag) .
In 1998, child tax allowances were available to families in the Czech
Republic (odpocty na deti), as well as in the majority of those Swiss
cantons (Kinderabzug/déduction pour enfants) that make use of fiscal
welfare in one way or another . They had also been fixed for several decades
in the German income tax code (1953-1974 and again 1983-1995; and, depending
on the perspective assumed, also during 1996-1998). In the Netherlands,
child tax allowances (kinderaftrek) were discontinued as early as 1978.
Hungary 'experimented' with child tax allowances between 1988 and 1991.
In the beginning only families with 3 and more children up to age 14 were
entitled. Later, the same deduction could be applied to children of birth
rank 1 and 2 under the age of 6. In 1992, the government terminated the
system of tax-base reduction, having been of rather modest size, and a
tax credit was introduced instead, with higher amounts for all children
with parity 3 and higher. These child tax credits were discontinued in
1994 as the first step of the austerity measures. In 1998, child tax credits
were reestablished, to be allocated from the fiscal year 2000 onwards.
During the 1990s, the Netherlands (since 1979) and Poland (which never
had legislated on child-related tax reliefs since the introduction of
personal income tax in 1992) organized a system of family income support
exclusively outside the tax system. 'With the crisis of the Dutch welfare
state in the first half of the 1970s, child allowances and tax allowances
for children were considered for reorganization and budget cuts' (Kuijsten/Schulze
2001). In a first stage, tax allowances for children were largely replaced
by higher child allowances in 1979.
Graph 4: Tax benefits for two children
as share of cash benefits for two children 1979-1998
Within the last two decades, eight out of the ten countries analysed
- the exceptions are the Netherlands and Poland - combined the two instruments
of social policy in order to realize public family support. Comparing
their relative weight across the countries considered, graph 4 suggests
that general child tax reliefs are predominantly legislated with the intention
to supplement the cash benefits. Austria, Belgium, and the Czech Republic
provide tax credits (Austria and Belgium) resp. tax allowances (Czech
Republic) that equal about one quarter to two fifth of the monetary transfers.
In the case of France, the graph does not represent an empirically existing
fiscal regulation. The French family splitting system rather demanded
a simulation in order to arrive at a fairly precise estimation of the
financial advantage linked to the family coefficient. The quotient of
about 60 to 70 percent (1985-1998) should be considered as a minimum share.
Important fiscal benefits are only available to French, German, and Luxembourg
(cf. above for futher explanations on Luxembourg) families with income
from employment on the APW level. The 100 percent share in the case of
Germany during 1996 to 1998 is explained by the OECD-classification of
familyrelated tax reliefs according to their functional logic in order
to arrive at the net family income . The rather stable relative shares
of child-related tax reliefs in most of the countries across time make
it plausible to assume that the measures of fiscal welfare are rather
regularly upgraded. Provisions for indexations of tax brackets, basic
exemptions and tax reliefs are empirically widespread in order to 'protect'
taxpayers against a (sustainably) weakened relative income position due
to inflation .
Comparison of married single earner with single person
The extent to which children are accounted for in the national income
tax systems can be estimated based on a juxtaposition of the relative
tax treatment of married couples with children with that of single childless
persons. In all countries, married couples pay (considerably) less taxes
than single persons with the same gross earnings. Empirically, the span
is rather high. The relative (total) advantage basically ranges between
11 to 17 percent in Switzerland (during the two decades), 14 to 16 percent
in the Netherlands (during the whole period) and Germany (until 1985),
and above 35 percent in Belgium (1990s) . For Austria, the difference
is fairly stable, amounting to about 25 percent. A high stability can
be observed for Luxembourg, too, on an even slightly higher level (30
to 33 percent). The income surplus shows more step changes in the Czech
Republic and Hungary, where the fourhead household was able to live on
about 20 to 30 percent more income than the single person during the second
half of the 1990s. It is surprising that the difference is narrowest in
Poland, amounting to merely 10 percent. Whereas Poland and Switzerland
combine a rather negligible relative (in cash) advantage for families
with a comparatively low income tax wedge, Austria and Belgium both apply
high average tax rates (including social contributions) and provide substantial
tax reliefs and cash benefits for families.
These variations in the quotient of tax liabilities are more pronounced
at lower income levels where the effects of exemptions and other spouse-
and child-related allowances predominate, whereas at higher earnings levels
the increasing marginal tax rates (on the assumption that progressive
tax schedules exist, as they do in all countries under investigation)
become most important, narrowing these differences. The relative advantage
of families also depends on the definition of the tax unit (joint or individual
filing of spouses or even children) and the usage of mechanisms of income
splitting amongst spouses or family members .
Graph 5a: Child-related income surplus
of married one-earner couple with two children compared to a single person
without children as share of his/her disposable household income, 1979-1998
Graph 5b: Child-related income surplus
of married one-earner couple with two children compared to a single person
without children as share of his/her disposable household income, 1979-1998
Graphs 5a and 5b represent the relative advantage in disposable household
income which can be attributed to those regulations of the tax-benefit-system
taking into consideration the presence of children. Other factors accounted
for by the OECD which could produce different outcomes under the assumptions
made above, are the tax-benefit rules related to (non-working) spouses
as well as the fiscal treatment of social security contributions and work-related
expenses . It goes without saying that both tax unit and tax schedule
play a key role, too. However, it would go beyond the scope of this contribution
to engage in any estimations of the combined influence on the differences
in net family income.
Comparing the percent income surplus left in the pocket of the one-earner
couple with two children, a first difference becomes obvious. In about
half of the nine countries included in the analysis - Germany, the Netherlands,
Poland, and Switzerland - all childrelated provisions of the tax-benefit
system globally contribute to a higher disposable income of only about
or below 10 percent. The income surplus amounts to about 20 to 25 percent
in Austria and Belgium and oscillates around 16 percent in France. In
other words, the relative advantage since the mid 1980s had amounted to
about one sixth, taking the net disposable household income of the single
person as the line of reference. Even if the clearly more advantageous
position of families by the mid 1990s continuously tended to erode in
the Czech Republic and Hungary, families are still considerably favoured.
In 1992, Hungary had even reached a maximum distance of about 43 percent:
Where the single person 'ends up' with 100 units of net family income
(in national currency), the tax-benefit-system attributes 143 units to
the one-earner couple with two children. Taken all together, this underlines
the globally important income effect related to the child-related provisions
in the tax-benefit system and the monetary transfers.
Graph 6a: Child related shares of income
surplus of married one earner couple with two children compared to single
person without children as share of his / her disposable household income
by instrument of family policy, 1979-1998
Graph 6b: Child related shares of income
surplus of married one earner couple with two children compared to single
person without children as share of his / her disposable household income
by instrument of family policy, 1979-1998
Graphs 6a and 6b present information that allows for a more comprehensive
evaluation of the combined effects of child allowances and fiscal advantages
as well as of their relative 'contribution'. The bars in the histograms
indicate to which extent child-related stipulations in the tax-benefit
system account for the differences in net household income when a married
couple with two children and one income is juxtaposed to a single person
without children. The relative proportion 'occupied' by cash benefits
or tax benefits within each bar shows how the two instruments of family
policy 'interact' in order to 'generate' the income surplus.
Within this context, Austria, France, and Hungary on the one hand and
Germany on the other represent the two poles. Whereas in the three countries
listed first the general child-related provisions of social and income
tax legislation accounted for about 75 to 98 percent of the income difference
between the two types of households analysed during the last two decades,
the graph for Germany clearly reflects the decisive 'position' of the
income splitting amongst spouses in relation to the global functioning
of the integral tax-benefit-system. The joint spouse taxation in Germany
provides a financial advantage of a weight quasi comparable to the joint
effects of the income transfers and the stipulations of the income tax
code for children. All other countries can be 'anchored' along this continuum
according to the relative importance of cash and tax benefits for children
compared to all other possible procedures to differentiate between a married
one-earner couple with two children and a single childless person.
Interplay of general cash and tax benefits for children
Before we consider the interplay of general cash and tax benefits with
these questions, let us recall the central questions: Is it possible to
depict a logic regarding the coordination of cash and tax benefits? Are
the tax reliefs conceptualized in such a way that they supplement the
monetary transfers or do they rather play an 'independent' role? Have
cash and tax benefits been substituted? To which extent does the inclusion
of tax reliefs for children alter the relative importance of public income
support compared to the analysis exclusively based on monetary transfers?
Finally: Will the broader perspective suggested in this article make it
necessary to reformulate the insight gained in terms of principal institutional
patterns and major tendencies of convergence and divergence between clusters
of countries, based on an analysis of monetary support given to families,
only?
In my opinion, it is not possible to find a clear pattern of coordinated
action by means of transfer and tax systems, both in a comparative perspective
and across time. As a rule, the tax reliefs are rather considered to be
a tool to supplement the cash benefits. Only in France, Germany, and Luxembourg
tax allowances and tax credits have greater independent weight. A ‚popular
strategy' is to compensate for the abolition of tax allowances by means
of an increase in the benefit rates of family allowances. Austria (in
1978) and Germany (1975) are good examples. For some countries, the patterns
generated on the basis of a separate quantitative and qualitative analysis
of child benefit payments are more or less reproduced. This holds for
Austria, Belgium, France, and Luxembourg. All four EU member countries
always 'come in' above the average. Rather often, they even 'end up' in
the top positions as regards public family support by means of the tax-benefit
system, i.e. all countries offer rather generous general cash and tax
benefits to families with children. This result seems to be strongly linked
to an institutional tradition they share, i.e. the organization as a separate
branch of social insurance, deeply inspired by the concept of a family
wage/salary. In all of these countries except for Luxembourg, the benefits
paid in a first phase after the implementation of the family benefit schemes
already reached a comparatively high level. The countries with a universal
scheme were not able to 'catch up' with this relative advantage before
the early 1990s - if at all. Other clusters did not become obvious. Especially
for the monetary transfer systems classified as ‚unfragmented' systems
above, one can hardly identify a basis for 'predicting' which major institutional
regulations will be the decisive ones. Here, Germany is a good example.
Across time the mixing of instruments was subject to several changes.
In addition, the relative weight of cash and tax benefits was rather often
adjusted.
One common property as to type of tax relief and tax basis should not
be overlooked, however: countries that apply a joint taxation of spouses
either seem to favour child tax allowances or have enacted a family splitting
system. From this perspective, France, Germany, Luxembourg, and Switzerland
are grouped together. The background variable shared by these countries
is the tax unit, itself influenced by the dominant concept of family (obligations).
The national fiscal legislation focuses on the family or household, which
are perceived as a unit of shared income and consumption, and not on the
individual adult. One can find additional support for this hypothesis
in extending the geographical scope to include Portugal, e.g. The only
country that does not fit into this logic is the Czech Republic, where
the individual assessment of income for spouses is combined with child
tax allowances. This feature has, however, to be seen in the light of
an institutional tradition dating from the socialist era, namely to tax
couples individually.
It might be too audacious to bring into play a last element. The Czech
Republic, Germany (at least until 1995), and Switzerland have implemented
a double-track system, aimed at increasing the family income via child
benefit and intended to guarantee an existence minimum of children exempt
of taxes via child tax allowances. If need be, poorer families are additionally
supported by locally administered social welfare benefits, in the Czech
Republic by means of the guaranteed existence minimum (životní
minimum/sociální príplatek), in Germany via social
assistance (Sozialhilfe). Offering rather generous monetary transfers
and tax credits, the French-speaking countries and Austria seem to favour
an instrument-mix which integrate stronger redistributional elements already
into the family support system in a proper sense.
Based on the analyses undertaken, it is not easy to arrive at a well-grounded
classification of the not yet 'consolidated' policies in Hungary. Both
sustained deficits during the phase of economic system transformation
and the lack of an institutional tradition of child-related fiscal welfare
after World War II have resulted in a continuous succession of changes.
Since 1996 the configuration has become more stable, as in the case of
the Czech Republic. Both countries put a considerable emphasis on this
social policy function already before 1990 and rather continue to do so
- in contrast to Poland which seems to share more common properties with
Portugal, e.g.. No outlayers can be identified for the Netherlands. As
to the public family support by cash and tax benefits and the effects
of the tax-benefit system they occupy a rank in the middle of the scale.
The relatively smaller shares of monetary transfers and fiscal advantages
in Switzerland should be more than compensated for by high average gross
wages and a comparatively low total tax wedge. In other words: The relative
'deficits' of the direct system of financial family support are likely
to be fairly well counter-balanced by comparative advantages brought about
indirectly (e.g. by means of level of earnings) or influenced by context
factors (e.g. by the design of system of social protection).
Notes
1 For the purpose of this article, the terms 'family allowances' and
'child benefit' are used synonymously.
2 In Belgium, the scheme has been administered by the National Institute
for Family Allowances for Salaried Workers and Employees (Office Nationale
d'Allocations Familiales des Travailleurs Salariés/ONAFTS) since
1944. In France, the former National Union of Family Allowances Funds
(Union Nationale des Caisses d'Allocations Familiales/UNCAF) was reorganized
in 1968 and renamed National Family Allowances Fund (Caisse Nationale
d'Allocations Familiales/CNAF). As regards Luxembourg, the four existing
agencies were merged to form one National Family Benefits Fund (Caisse
Nationale des Prestations Familiales/CNPF) in 1985.
3 Cf. e.g. Laroque 1985 for a detailed, chronological description.
4 The deep decrease of the real value of this social benefit 'was a far
greater problem than making it dependent on a certain level of income.
By 1996, the real value of family allowance received by a family with
two children was only 40 percent of its value compared to 1990; in case
of a family with three or more children, it was 45 percent' (Tárkányi
2001).
5 'Haunted by hyperinflation, the beginning of the transition period brought
about changes in the principles for granting the family allowance. No
longer quota-based, it was linked to specific parameters and amounted
to 8% of average wages. (…) The decline in wages was so dramatic that
the parameter-based identification of the amount of the allowance was
soon withdrawn. In 1992, the allowance stood at 7% of average net wages.
The amount was not indexed and at the time annual inflation was running
at 30%. (…) To date, identified amounts are indexed once a year in line
with the price increase index. Due to the fact that Polish wages have
dramatically increased since 1994, price indexation of family benefits
has had a negative effect on the benefit-to-wages rate. After two years,
the value of the benefit had fallen to approximately 6% of average wages'
(Golinowska 2001).
6 'The ascription of certain sums of money to specific age groups (…)
rests upon economic research which is done repeatedly' (Kuijsten/Schulze
2001).
7 The instrument of linking family allowances to the income level is commonly
used by all southern European EU member countries. Incometesting, grading
by income groups and withdrawal of benefit payments above a certain limit
is in force in Italy and Spain. Greece and Portugal operated with a progressive
reduction according to an increase in household income in 1998.
8 The only exception is Germany. Even if no income test had been applied
for familes with only one child ever since the entitlement to the child
benefit was extended to include children of birth rank 1 in 1975, thresholds
were reintroduced in 1983 for families with 2 or more children. As in
France one and a half decade later, they were fixed on a relatively high
level. Until 1995 a progressive reduction according to an increase in
household income was applied, however, concerning rather affluent families
only. The enactment of this measure had been pushed by considerations
concerning both cost containment and more adequate targeting.
9 The following ECU amounts were paid to entitled families with three
children in 1998 on a monthly basis (without possible age supplement and
disregarding possible income thresholds): A: 260; B: 371; CH (canton of
Zurich): 201; CZ: 71-103, depending on age group; D: 331; F: 335; H: 149;
L: 478; NL: 204; PL: 65 (MISSOC 1999; OECD 1999; Maucher/Bahle 2000).
They are adjusted for purchasing power parities.
10 This measure clearly is rather sensitive to economic growth rates and
the apportionment of the net national product at factor cost by type (gross
earned income from employment, entrepreneurial income, and property income
As we do not use deflators in order to determine both the national income's
and the child benefit's value at constant prices, we have to argue cautiously
as regards the specific impact of general cash transfers to families on
the varying shares.
11 They were discontinued as early as 1938.
12 In all graphs presenting cash benefits, the data for Switzerland exclusively
refer to the canton of Zurich. Since the introduction of child benefit
payments in 1958, the 'size' of benefits provided by the cantonal family
allowances fund has always been quasi identical with the Swiss mean. The
data can therefore be considered to be highly representative for the whole
country.
13 'Despite the major economic cycles, demographic shifts, and financial
problems of the welfare state over the last thirty years, family allowances
remained important and benefits have kept pace with rising incomes' (Bahle
2001) due to regular adjustment for inflation.
14 The following ECU amounts were paid to entitled families with two children
aged 15 in 1998, i.e. including possible age supplements, disregarding
possible income thresholds: A: 206; B: 224; CH (canton of Zurich): 134;
CZ: 22-71, depending on age group; D: 197; F: 261; H: 40-78, depending
on family income; L: 271; NL: 137; PL: 38 (MISSOC 1999; OECD 1999; Maucher/Bahle
2000). They are monthly benefits, standardized by purchasing power parities.
15 It was only in the 1990s that Finland, Norway, and Portugal introduced
benefit increases for children below age 3 (for details cf. Bahle/Maucher
2001). Their enactment is grounded on the consideration that higher expenses
for baby equipment, especially for the first child, should at least partly
be compensated for.
16 Having principally excluded the former Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and
Poland from the analysis on the relative importance of family allowances
with reference to the average gross wages, the following data are intended
to give a certain idea on the relevance of child benefit payments for
one of the central European OECD member countries for the phase prior
to 1990: Until 1960, the average amount of had stagnated and then was
increased significantly. 'Already in 1980, it was remarkably high, even
in international comparison' (Tárkányi 2001). The child
benefit made up for about a quarter of the average wages, compared to
15-20 percent in other socialist countries. The exact values for a couple
with two children for the period 1950-1998 are as follows: 1950: 5.9;
1955: 6.6; 1960: 4.8; 1965: 11.3; 1970: 14.0; 1975: 20.8; 1980: 24.4;
1985: 24.2; 1990: 34.3; 1995: 20.6; 1998: 16.6. With an additional child,
these shares - up to 1990 - increase remarkably, which clearly underlines
their economic importance for larger families: 1950: 9.7; 1955: 15.8;
1960: 22.9; 1965: 20.4; 1970: 23.8; 1975: 33.3; 1980: 49.3; 1985: 43.0;
1990: 54.5; 1995: 23.8; 1998: 21.8. (Based on Tárkányi 2001)
17 The financially more advantageous position of employees is a feature
common to all six countries included into the analysis. The cross-country
variations represented in graph 2b are consequently linked to different
relative weights of economic sectors in a country as well as to three
ratios: workers/employees, male employment/female employment and full-time
work/part-time work. Their branch-specific combinations summed up across
all sectors then determine the wage differential as reflected in the mean
values for the two occupational groups. Since the mid 1970s resp. mid
1950s, the distance as regards labour market income between those two
occupational groups as a whole became narrower in France (1975: 1.34;
1995: 1.07) resp. Switzerland (1955: 1.63; 1975: 1.54; 1995: 1.22). In
Austria (1955: 1.61; 1995: 1.49), Belgium (1965: 1.73; 1992: 1.52), and
Germany (1955: 1.51; 1995: 1.29) the gap had been bigger during the 1950s
and 1960s. Since then it has tended to decrease. The Luxembourg employees,
however, have continuously increased their relative financial advantage
during the last two decades (1978: 1.39; 1998: 1.89). The values in parantheses
are the multipliers to be entered into the equation in order to arrive
at the average income of employees, given the average income of workers.
18 Several inquiries into the income tax treatment of families in OECD
countries have underlined the lack of consistency in terms of how the
particular characteristics of the family are taken into consideration
in determining tax liabilities differentiated by house-hold type/family
composition. Several major topics in cross-country analyses of family
taxation can be distinguished. Most of them centre around the issues of
marriage neutrality, horizontal equity between married couples - in case
the spouses contribute to the family income at a proportion different
from 50 percent each -, and progressiveness of the tax schedule (Pechmann/Engelhardt
1990; O'Donoghue/Sutherland 1998; Dingeldey 1999 and 2000). Following
the tradition of both labour economy research and welfare state analysis
which focuses on gender differences, a major concern consisted in identifying
incentives and restrictions for female labour market participation associated
to specific models of welfare states and sets of social policies (cf.
OECD 1977; Cnossen/Messere 1990; Parker/Sutherland 1991; Dingeldey 1999
and 2000; Soler Roch 1999). Based on helpful systematizations of tax base
and tax rate issues related to marriage, cohabitation, inheritage and
children (Cnossen/Messere 1990; O'Donoghue/Sutherland 1998), several pieces
of research contributed to a clearer understanding of the rather complex
and nontransparent effects of different taxation systems and specific
income tax regulations on disposable household income of different types
of families with children. They helped to explain which distributional
effects the national tax-benefit system produce with regard to the net
income of two earner vs. one-earner married couples. However, they did
not systematically link child-related tax with cash benefits, as e.g.
Stropnik et al. (1996) in comparing the 'global performance' of governmental
support of families in Austria, Croatia and Slovenia during the 1990s.
They show how standard tax reliefs (basic and dependents-related) are
reflected in the individual/family tax burden, and what is the joint impact
of tax savings and child benefits on family disposable income.
19 Other child-related deductions or exemptions, e.g. for children with
specific needs due to a handicap, for children of single parents or costs
of child care outside the family are left aside.
20 The analyses are mainly based on OECD data and information (OECD 1977;
{1}-{3}; 1999); they are supplemented, however, by several other sources
(IBFD 1990-2000; Lohaus 1997) in order to fill gaps or to resolve inconsistencies.
21 The Luxembourg income tax code, e.g., used a coefficient of 3.4 in
1984 for a couple with two children, which was even increased to 3.8 in
1990. Since the establishment of the family splitting, France has operated
with a factor of 3 for the same household type. The family splitting approach
noticeably reduces the taxable income which is divided by this family
quotient and then applied to the tax schedule in the same manner as for
a single person. 'Total tax for the unit is found by multiplying this
calculated tax by the family quotient' (O'Donoghue/Sutherland 1998: 45).
22 After having discontinued the family splitting system, the maximum
income effect of the tax credit is limited to a maximum amount, equal
to about 140 percent of the corresponding family allowances for two children
in 1991. It had decreased to about two thirds of the cash benefit in 1998.
As early as 1981, the French legislator had fixed a maximum advantage
related to the child's coefficient which - during the 1990s - amounted
to about 220 to 290 percent of the estimated effect for an APW as represented
in graph 3.
23 Portugal e.g. is a counterexample. (At least) During the 1980s until
their discontinuation in 1988, the child tax allowances were increased
for children aged 11 and older.
24 'Tax relief' is used as a generic term to cover all the means of giving
favourable income tax treatment to persons in gainful employment, married
or cohabiting couples and heads of families for their children or other
dependent relatives.
25 Tax credits are amounts which a tax payer may subtract from his/her
tax liability, once gross taxes have been calculated. Most commonly applied
to fixed amounts, their value (under this hypothesis) does not depend
on income. Tax credits are considered an instrument in order to arrive
at more vertical equity. Consequently they rather serve distributional
purposes.
26 Family coefficient taxation involves the aggregation of income within
the tax unit. 'Total taxable income is divided by a family coefficient
and then applied to the tax schedule in the same manner as for a single
person. Total tax for the unit is found by multiplying this calculated
tax by the family coefficient' (O'Donoghue/Sutherland 1998: 45) to arrive
at the family tax liability. Tax splitting amongst spouses - as applied,
e.g., in Germany since 1957 (Ehegattensplitting) - can be interpreted
as one special case in family splitting systems, using a coefficient of
2.
27 Except for the period 1975-1982, it had been under operation since
the mid 1950s.
28 For families with a high income - i.e. for taxpayers with a marginal
rate of at least 38 percent, i.e. about 5% of the families entitled to
child benefit in 1998 -, the rationale (solution) is to opt for child
tax allowances for children of birth rank 1 and 2. For all subsequent
children the amount of the child benefit is equal to or higher than the
fiscal effects brought about by the tax child allowance. For income subject
to the highest rates within the progression zone - reaching a peak value
of 53 percent in 1998 -, the child tax allowance represented a maximum
advantage of around 300 DM per head (cf. Wingen 1997: 233). According
to the legislator's intention, it is exclusively the amount left over,
having ensured a 100 percent exemption of children's existence minimum
at whatever income level, that is earmarked for redistributive purposes.
29 'Tax allowances are amounts substracted from the tax base - i.e. the
incomes which are taxable (remark by the author) - to arrive at the income
on which tax is levied' (O'Donoghue/Sutherland 1998: 46). This instrument,
synonymously often called 'tax deduction', generally is a main pillar
of systems with progressive income tax schedules, i.e. 'the set of thresholds
and tax rates that determine the amount of tax collected from a specific
taxable income' (O'Donoghue/Sutherland 1998: 46). As to their effects,
they can be thought of as zero-rate tax bands, too. Based on the 'ability-to-pay-principle'
tax allowances focus on horizontal equity and efficiency. Their rationale
follows a 'tax capacity approach', i.e. the tax schedule is only applied
on income in excess of the subsistence income. Child-related tax allowances
aim at compensating for family obligations at the marginal rate of the
individual tax payer. This is why their implementation asks for a integral
view on the tax and transfer system.
30 'Some cantons (eight cantons in 1973, nine in 1995) provide tax allowances
for children which are progressive by parity, an obviously pronatalist
feature. A smaller sample of cantons (...) entitles parents to tax credits.
There is no clear pattern that would explain which option is chosen by
a canton. Again, the quantitative development is highly correlated with
economic growth and indicates no marked increase in family-related transfers'
(Fux 2001).
31 It builds upon the benefit's design as 'guaranteed transfer' for all
families - a functional equivalent to a ‚refundable/non-wastable tax credit'.
According to the revised system of equalizing family burdens, it is provided
in form of a tax credit. The entitlement to a tax allowance worth a higher
amount is only given to families in the upper decile of the income distribution
for children of birth rank 1 and 2.
32 Even in Germany, both child benefit and child tax allowance have been
regularly upgraded in line with the existence minimum since 1996. For
more detailed information cf. OECD 1977, 1978/1980, 1980/1981/1982/1983,
various years, 1999; Cnossen/Messere 1990; IFBD, various years; O'Donoghue/Sutherland
1998).
33 Those values are obtained by multiplying the percent shares in graphs
5a and 5b with the quotients of income surplus related to the presence
of children, as reflected in graphs 6a and 6b.
34 Wheras Austria, Belgium, the Czech Republic, Hungary, the Netherlands,
and Poland had implemented a separate assessment of individuals in their
national income tax codes - implying no advantages for single earners
-, Germany, Luxembourg, and Switzerland operated with a system of a joint
assessment of spouses in 1998. As to the effects, the same can be said
for France which used a joint assessment of the house-hold/family members.
In this year, France has been the only European country to (still) apply
a family splitting system. Regulations on joint assessment as a rule go
hand in hand with a broader definition of family and family obligations
in family and social law, as it is the case e.g. for Germany. If a tax
system is to realize a maximum neutrality towards marital status, labour
offer and the division of time spent with child raising, then separate
assessment is the only solution.
References
Äschbach, Silvia (1980). Die Besteuerung der Familie in Deutschland,
Österreich und Frankreich im Vergleich zur Schweiz. Zürich:
Juris Druck + Verlag.
Atkinson, Anthony Barnes (1995). 'On targeting and family benefits'. In:
Atkinson, Anthony Barnes, Incomes and the Welfare State. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 223-261.
Bahle, Thomas (2001, forthcoming). 'Germany'. Unpublished country report.
International project 'Family Changes and Family Policies in the West,
coordinated by the MZES, Mannheim.
Bradshaw, Jonathan, John Ditch, Hilary Holmes, and Peter Whiteford (1993).
Support for Children. A comparison of arrangements in fifteen countries.
London: HMSO (Series: Department of Social Security: Research Report No.
21).
Bundesministerium der Finanzen [BMF] (2001). Übersichten zur Einkommensteuer-Tarifbelastung
von 1958-2002: Grenzbelastung - Splittingtabelle; Steuerberechnung für
Einkommensteuerpflichtige - verheiratet. Berlin: BMF (http://www.bundesfinanzministerium.de/fach/tarife/start.htm).
Caisse National des Allocations Familiales [CNAF] (1995). Analyse et simulation
de politiques de prestations familiales en Europe. Une comparaison entre
la France, l'Allemagne, la Belgique, l'Irlande et le Luxembourg. Paris:
CNAF.
Cnossen, Sijbren and Ken Messere (1990). Income Tax Reforms in OECD Member
Countries. International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation: Bulletin, October
1990: 463-483.
Council of Europe [CE] (1997). Comparative tables of social security schemes
in Council of Europe member states, not member of the European Union,
in Australia and Canada (8th edition/situation as of 1 July 1996). Strasbourg:
CE.
Cervenková, Iva (1993). Právní úprava sociálního
pojištení od roku 1993 (= Legal regulations for the social insurance
in 1993). Praha: Eurounion.
Cervenková, Iva (1994). Dodatek k právní úprave
sociálního pojištení. Komentár ke zmenám
predpisu v sociálním zabezpecení k 1.1.1994 (= Supplement
to legal regulations for the social insurance. Commentary on amendments
to stipulations on social insurance as of 1.1.1994). Praha: Eurounion.
Ceský Statistický Úrad [CSU]/Czech Statistical Office
(various years: 1995; 1999). Statistická Rocenka Ceské Republiky/Statistical
Yearbook of the Czech Republic. Praha: CSU.
Dingeldey, Irene (1999). International Comparison of Tax Systems and their
Impact on the Work-Family Balancing. Gelsenkirchen: Institut für
Arbeit und Technik.
Dingeldey, Irene, ed. (2000). Erwerbstätigkeit und Familie in Steuer-
und Sozialversicherungssystemen. Opladen: Leske & Budrich, 2000.
Ebert, Udo (1997). Einige Überlegungen zur Familienbesteuerung. Oldenburg:
Uni Oldenburg/Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre I (Series: Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche
Diskussionspapiere V-181-97).
European Observatory on National Family Policies [EONFP] (various years:
1995; 1996; 1998). Developments in National Family Policies. Keighley:
Fretwell Print and Design.
Filipic, Ursula (1998). 'Soziale Sicherung in Tschechien'. In Tálos,
Emmerich, ed. Soziale Sicherung im Wandel. Österreich und seine Nachbarstaaten.
Ein Vergleich. Wien: Böhlau Verlag, 365-437.
Flora, Peter, ed. (1986/1987). Growth to limits. The Western European
Welfare States since World War II. Berlin: de Gruyter.
Frerich, Johannes and Martin Frey (1993). Handbuch der Geschichte der
Sozialpolitik in Deutschland. Band 3: Sozialpolitik in der Bundesrepublik
Deutschland bis zur Herstellung der Deutschen Einheit. München: Oldenbourg.
Fux, Beat (2001, forthcoming). 'Switzerland'. Unpublished country report.
International project 'Family Changes and Family Policies in the West,
coordinated by the MZES, Mannheim.
Gauthier, Anne Hélène (1999). Historical Trends in State
Support for Families in Europe (post-1945). Children and Youth Services
Review, 21(11/12): 937-65.
Glowny Urzad Statystyczny [GUS]/Central Statistical Office (various years:
1995; 1998). Rocznik Statystyczny Rzeczypospolitej Polskiej/Statistical
Yearbook of the Republic of Poland. Warszawa: GUS.
Golinowska, Stanislawa, (2001, forth-coming). 'Poland'. Unpublished country
report. International project 'Family Changes and Family Policies in the
West, coordinated by the MZES, Mannheim.
Hungarian Central Statistical Office [HCSO] (2001). Major annual figures:
Wages, earnings: Average gross earnings of employees, HUF/month. Budapest:
HCSO (http://www.ksh.hu/eng/free/e6/e60301.html).
Immervoll, Herwig, Holly Sutherland, and Klaas de Vos (1999). Reducing
Child Poverty in the European Union: The Role of Child Benefits. (Conference:
Child Well-Being in Rich and Transition Countries. Are Children in Growing
Danger of Social Exclusion? Dommeldange/L).
International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation [IBFD] (various years: 1990-2000).
European Tax Handbook. Amsterdam: IBFD Publications BV.
International Labour Organization [ILO] (1998-2001). Labour Statistics
Database (ILO Bureau of Statistics). Geneva: ILO (http://laborsta.ilo.org/).
Kahn, Sheila B. and Alfred J. Kahn (1978). Government and families in
forteen countries. New York: Columbia University Press.
Kahn, Sheila B. and Alfred J. Kahn (1991). Government expenditures for
children and their families in advanced industrialized countries, 1960-85.
Florence: United Nations Children's Fund/International Child Development
Centre (Innocenti Occasional Papers. Economic and Social Policy Series
No. 20).
Kahn, Sheila B. and Alfred J. Kahn (1994). Social Policy and the Under-3s.
Six Country Case Studies. New York: Columbia University Press.
Kahn, Sheila B. and Alfred J. Kahn (1997): 'Investing in children: government
expenditure for children and their families in Western industrialized
countries'. In Cornia, G.A. and S. Danziger, eds. Child poverty and deprivation
in the industrialized countries 1945-95. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 91-121.
Központi Statisztikai Hivatal [KSH]/Hungarian Central Statistical
Office (various years: 1994; 1998). Magyar Statisztikai Évkönyv/Statistical
Yearbook of Hungary. Budapest: KSH.
Kuijsten, Anton/Schulze, Hans-Joachim (2001, forthcoming). 'The Netherlands'.
Unpublished country report. International project 'Family Changes and
Family Policies in the West, coordinated by the MZES, Mannheim.
Laroque, Pierre (1985). La politique familiale en France depuis 1945.
Paris: Ministère des Affaires Sociales et de la Solidarité
Nationale/Commisariat Général au Plan.
Lohaus, Jutta (1997). Die Entwicklung der Familienbesteuerung im deutschen
und englischen Einkommensrecht. Münster: Westfälische Wilhelms-Universität.
Maucher, Mathias and Thomas Bahle, eds. (2000). MZES/EURODATA Family Policy
Database. Mannheim: MZES.
Messere, Ken (1993). Tax Policy in OECD Countries. Choices and Conflicts.
Amsterdam: IBFD Publications BV.
Millar, Jane and Andrea Warman, eds. (1995). Defining family obligations
in Europe. Bath: University of Bath (Series: Bath Social Policy Papers
No. 23).
Ministère Fédéral du Travail et des Affaires Sociales/Ministères
du Travail et des Affaires Sociales des Républiques Socialistes
Tchèque et Slovaque/Conseil Central des Syndicats, ed. (1977).
Les certitudes sociales en Tchécoslovaquie. Prague: Práce
- Maison d'édition du Mouvement syndical révolutionnaire.
Mitchell, Deborah (1991), Income transfers in ten welfare states. Aldershot:
Avebury (Series: Studies in Cash & Care).
Mutual Information System on Social Protection (MISSOC) (1996). Soziale
Sicherheit in den Mitgliedsstaaten der Europäischen Union. Stand
am 1. Juli 1995 und Entwicklung. Luxemburg: Amt für amtliche Veröffentlichungen
der Europäischen Gemeinschaften.
Mutual Information System on Social Protection (MISSOC) (1999). Social
Protection in the Member States of the European Union. Situation on 1
January 1998 and evolution. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications
of the European Communities.
Neubauer, Erika, Christiane Dienel and Marlene Lohkamp-Himmighofen (1993).
Zwölf Wege der Familienpolitik in der Europäischen Gemeinschaft.
Eigenständige Systeme und vergleichbare Qualitäten? Stuttgart:
Kohlhammer (Series: Schriftenreihe des Bundesministeriums für Familie
und Senioren 22.1).
Observatoire Européen des Politiques Familiales Nationales [OEPFN]/Dumont,
Wilfried, ed. (1994). Évolution des Politiques Familiales dans
les États Membres de l'Union Européenne. Bruxelles: Commission
des Communautés Européennes/DG V.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development [OECD] (1977). The
treatment of family units in the OECD member countries under tax and transfer
systems. Paris: OCDE.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development [OECD] (various
years: 1978; 1980) {1}. The tax/benefit position of selected income groups
in OECD member countries. Paris: OECD.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development [OECD] (various
years: 1980-1983) {2}. The tax/benefit position a typical worker in OECD
member countries. Paris: OECD.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development [OECD], (various
years: 1985-1998) {3}. The tax/benefit position of production workers.
Paris: OECD.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development [OECD] (1999). Taxing
wages 1998-1999. Paris: OECD.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development [OECD] (2000). Statistical
compendium. Paris: OECD.
O'Donoghue, Cathal and Holly Sutherland (1998). Accounting for the Family:
The Treatment of Marriage and Children in European Income Tax Systems.
Florence: United Nations Children's Fund/International Child Development
Centre (Innocenti Occasional Papers. Economic and Social Policy Series
No. 65).
Parker, Hermione and Holly Sutherland (1991). Child Tax Allowances? A
comparison of child benefit, child tax reliefs, and basic incomes as instruments
of family policy. London: London School of Economics and Political Science.
(Series: Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related
Disciplines: Occasional Papers 16).
Pechman, Joseph A. and Gary V. Engelhardt (1990). The income tax treatment
of the family: An international perspective. In National Tax Journal,
43(1): 1-22.
Sociale Verzekeringsbank [SVB] (2001). Kinderbijslag (AKW): Kinderbijslag
bedragen en betaling (= Child beneft (General Child Benefit Law): Child
benefit amount and payment). Amstelveen: SVB (http://www.svb.org/index_small.html?envelope=122&folder=m88).
Soler Roch, María Teresa, ed. (1999). Family taxation in Europe.
The Hague: Kluwer Law International.
Tárkányi, Ákos (2001, forthcoming). 3.2 Families
and Taxation & 3.3 Family Benefits. In Spéder, Zsolt. 'Hungary'.
Unpublished country report. International project 'Family Changes and
Family Policies in the West, coordinated by the MZES, Mannheim.
Service central de la statistique et des études économiques
[STATEC] (various years: 1982-2000). Annuaire statistique. Luxembourg:
STATEC.
Statistical Office of the European Communities [EUROSTAT] (2000). New
Cronos. Luxembourg: EUROSTAT.
Storka, Blanka (1995). Sozialversicherung in Tschechien. Ein praxisnaher
Leitfaden. Wien: Verlag Österreich/Berlin Verlag Arno Spitz, 1995.
Stropnik, Nada, Helena Blazic, and Sabine Kristen (1996). Vpliv otroških
dodatkov in davcnih olajšav za otroke na razpoložljive družinske dohodke
(= The impact of child allowances and tax allowances for children on family
disposable income). Slovenska ekonomska revija (= Slovenian Economic Review),
47(4): 292-314.
Thöni, Erich and Hannes Winner, eds., (1996). Die Familie im Sozialstaat.
Familienbesteuerung aus ökonomischer und juristischer Sicht. Innsbruck:
Leopold-Franzens-Universität Innsbruck.
Wendt, Claus and Mathias Maucher (2000). Mütter zwischen Kinderbetreuung
und Erwerbstätigkeit: Institutionelle Hilfen und Hürden bei
einem beruflichen Wiedereinstieg nach einer Kinderpause. Mannheim: MZES
(Series: MZES Arbeitspapiere/Working Papers No. 18).
Wennemo, Irene (1994). Sharing the Costs of Children. Studies on the Development
of Family Support in the OECD countries. Edsbruk: Akademitryck AB.
Wingen, Max (1997). Familienpolitik. Stuttgart: Lucius & Lucius.
Wörister, Karl (1998). 'Soziale Sicherung in Ungarn'. In Tálos,
Emmerich, ed. Soziale Sicherung im Wandel. Österreich und seine Nachbarstaaten.
Ein Vergleich. Wien: Böhlau Verlag, 289-364.
The author thanks Thomas Bahle, MZES, and Claus Wendt, University of
Heidelberg, for critical, helpful comments. He is indebted to Stefan Kühner,
MZES, for data collection and analysis, as well as especially for the
production of the graphs.
Mathias Maucher
Mannheim Centre for European Social Research, EURODATA/AB I
L7,1, 68131 Mannheim
Tel: 0049(0)621-181-2830
Fax: 0049(0)621-181-2834
E-mail: mathias.maucher@mzes. uni-mannheim.de
Mathias Maucher has graduated in administrative sciences and works as
a researcher at the EURODATA Research Archive. He is manager of the MZES/EURODATA
Family Policy Database. In a joint ILO/EURODATA project he works on establishing
a database on ILO's inquiry 'The Cost of Social Security'
|